A Guest Post in english By Kevin Gentle - By courtesy of The Institut Hayek of Brussels
Ever
since China started opening up to the world in 1978, it has been
praised for its achievements. In a mere 30 years, China has gone from a
backward agrarian based economy plagued by inefficiency and
mismanagement to a global industrial powerhouse flooding the world with
its products. In the process, the country has lifted millions out of
poverty and now looks to the future with unrestrained optimism.
Nonetheless,
as the world looks to China to lead the global recovery, many tend to
overlook the flaws and imbalances of the Chinese economy and
underestimate the challenges that lie ahead. Following a brute force
development model based on subsidized industry and manufacturing is one
thing, but evolving into a 21st century knowledge based economy led by a
vibrant private sector and a dynamic domestic market will require
further efforts and far reaching reforms that will change the very core
of the Chinese system.
This essay will argue that while
china’s achievements have indeed been remarkable, it does not follow a
sustainable growth path and needs to end its reliance on investment and
export and develop its domestic consumer market in order to join the
club of developed economies. We will also describe how counter crisis
measures taken by the Chinese government have exacerbated China’s
problems and do not constitute a long-term solution to the economy’s
woes.
What's exactly the chinese model ?
Since
2004 china has devoted an average of 40% of its GDP to investment. This
figure far exceeds that of South Korea or Taiwan at the height of their
investment led development. These investments derive directly from
China’s development strategy based on exports and manufacturing. All in
all, industrial output accounts for nearly half of china’s GDP and
services for a mere 40%. As of today, if we look at the structure of its
economy, China looks more like a communist country than a capitalist
one. What’s more, the stimulus plan is likely to raise the share of
investment to over 50% of GDP in 2009, this accentuating the imbalances
the government was trying to correct before the crisis started.
The
high level of industrial investment is a direct corollary of China’s
export led development. For years, the country has produced far more
than it could consume and has acted as the world’s manufacturing base.
Such a strategy was made possible by cheap credit, high debt levels and
distorted financial markets in the west (especially in the USA). Ever
since the 90’s, saving rates in the US have steadily declined until
becoming negative before the crisis started in 2008. However, what can’t
go on forever won’t.
Such a situation could only be ephemera
and led to the current crisis. Thinking that exports will pick up and
reach their previous levels is downright foolish. World demand will
never play the same role than during the last decade and what is
troubling is that China seems to have based its development on an
abnormality. In the years to come, western consumers will scale down
their debt and governments will be forced to massively slash deficits.
Consumption will fall and China cannot count on western consumers to
power its development. The fact that industry investment figures are
still rising at a greater pace than domestic demand (especially consumer
demand) raises questions as to whether China is prepared to change its
development model.
Massive trade surpluses
As a
result of its export oriented model, China been able to run massive
trade surpluses in the last decade. Such surpluses created excess
capital, which were reinvested in assets (mainly US treasury bonds) and
fuelled the investment frenzy. However, a country’s importance rests on
the size of its economy, not on that of its surpluses. Export strategies
and trade surpluses did not shield Germany and Japan from the
recession. Moreover, running huge surpluses and reinvesting them into
foreign assets is a dubious strategy. Massive trade deficits do indeed
exert a downward pressure on a country’s currency. As a result, if the
Chinese accumulate surpluses and reinvest them into foreign assets, the
value of these assets is likely to decline. Experience shows that
surplus countries’ net external asset position is always far less than
the sum of their surpluses over the years.
Now, as world demand
picks up but looks unlikely to reach its previous levels, the spectre of
spare capacity looms and domestic demand needs to absorb the extra
production. In 2009, extra government demand generated by the stimulus
plan has allowed China to avoid a downturn but stimulus measures won’t
last forever and they are strong indications that China is experiencing
artificial short term growth. In 2009, Chinese authorities have shown
impressive determination in their efforts to ramp up internal demand and
have, to some extent, been successful. Government measures have
stimulated the automobile and household devices markets and retail sales
have increased by 15,2% in the 12 months to May 2009. Nonetheless,
retail sales include sales to government organization and do not reflect
real consumer demand. In reality, consumption by urban households has
increase by only 8,1%, less than income. These figures are not alarming
but clearly show that China has a long way to go towards stimulating its
domestic consumer market.
Wen Jiabao: "Enhance the role of domestic demand"
Premier
Wen Jiabao himself has recently stated that “We should make greater
efforts to enhance the role of domestic demand, especially consumption“.
It is indeed troubling to see that household consumption represents a
paltry 35% of GDP while this figure is 67% in India. If it is to join
the club of advanced economies, China must go beyond industry and
exports and evolve into a service-based economy relying on its domestic
market.
These two changes go hand in hand. Indeed, as the
Chinese grow richer, they will devote a larger share of their income to
services. The shift towards a service economy will allow china the
rebalance its system on two fronts. In order to achieve this
transformation, China should, among other things, shift its taxation
burden, allow RMB strengthening, liberalize labour markets and continue
the process of liberalization of financial services. As of today, the
burden of taxation is on consumption while many companies pay little
taxes and thus over invest in new production capacities. Shifting the
taxation burden would allow to increase disposable household income
while stemming the investment frenzy.
RMB liberalization would
put an end to an implicit export subsidy. Not only would it boost real
income, and thus encourage consumption through imports, but it would
also force companies to innovate and generate productivity gains to stay
competitive, thus departing from the previous labour intensive
production model generating low value added and razor thin margins.
China’s rigid labour market makes it hard for workers to change jobs and
thus keep real wages at a level incompatible with a consumer spending
based economy. By putting an end to the Hukou system and making it
easier for workers to move around and change jobs (mainly through the
elimination of administrative authorizations), the Chinese government
would allow real wages and consumer spending to rise. Recent talks by
high-ranking officials to eliminate the Hukou system, or at least make
it more flexible, are extremely encouraging and it looks like the
Chinese government is moving towards greater flexibility in the labour
market. Finally, reform of the financial system should encourage more
lending to households and less lending to state owned companies. Indeed,
real interest rates on loans to state owned companies are kept
artificially low which encourages over investment in capital intensive
industries and keeps consumer credit and mortgage markets
underdeveloped. Here again signs or progress are encouraging and we have
seen in the second semester of 2009 a sensible rise in consumer credit.
Stimulus and imbalances
Ever
since the Chinese government announced its 4 trillion RMB stimulus
plan, it has been praised for throwing the kitchen sink at the problem
and injecting much needed confidence into financial markets. The short
term results of the plan have indeed been staggering, China is expected
to hit a 9 to 10% GDP growth rate in 2009 and people the world over look
to China to lead the recovery. Nonetheless, the plan’s structure and
ripple effect have aggravated in many ways china’s economy’s imbalances
and put a stop the train of reforms.
First of all the plan has
mainly benefited state owned enterprises at the expenses of the private
sector. We are currently seeing a new wave of nationalization led from
the bottom up, fuelled by cheap credit and motivated by local official’s
vested interests. Business environment has been soured by signs that
the government is not as committed to reforms as was previously though.
Such moves delay the emergence of a real private sector and, if not
reversed, may hamper China’s future development. Government meddling
also means greater focus on industry and makes even more difficult the
task of rebalancing the structure of China’s economy.
Then, the
government has also addressed the crisis by ordering banks to lend
virtually limitless amounts of money to SOEs. Analysts agree that
considering the number and size of the loans granted, banks cannot have
conducted proper risk analysis and will most likely find themselves with
an increasing share of Non Performing Loans in their portfolios.
Massive
lending also fuels investment bubbles. The threat is aggravated by the
intrinsic volatility of China’s markets (the Shanghai stock market is
often nicknames “the great lottery”). Lack of credible information from
companies (especially state owned) and the government (many figures
often differ whether you look at central government or local government
figures) encourages blind speculation and makes many economists fret
about the consequences of the investment boom.
Conclusion
In
the end, the Chinese economy will, for better or worst, be the driving
force of the 2010’s world economy. Its potential is enormous but so are
the challenges it faces. As we know, China’s achievements during the
last 3 decades have been truly unique and they is no reason to doubt
that the Chinese government has the capacity to implement the changes
necessary to rebalance the economy. Nonetheless the train of reforms
must be put back on track very quickly and deep structural changes
cannot wait long before these imbalances translate into more serious
issues.
© 2010/09 - Kevin Gentle & Institut Hayek
-----------------
More China-nomics on Objectif Liberte (in French - By Vincent Benard)
- Chine : moteur de la reprise ou prochaine bulle ?
- Chine, USA, un bulletin économique pessimiste
- Ordos ville fantôme (vidéo)
- Chine, une bulle immobilière d'origine étatique
----------------
Je reviens juste sur le point suivant :
> Such surpluses created excess capital, which
> were reinvested in assets
> (mainly US treasury bonds)
Pour rappel, la chine, si elle est le premier détenteur étranger en volume de bons du trésors américain (juste devant le japon), ne détient pour autant qu'une vingtaine de % de la dette publique américaine détenue par des étrangers, qui ne représente elle même que le quart de la dette publique américaine au total. Soit en fait 5% de la dette publique américaine. Et ce chiffre baisse désormais, en absolu comme en relatif (http://www.ustreas.gov/tic/mfh.txt).
Si l'on compare ce chiffre au déficit de la balance commerciale américaine avec la chine sur les 10 dernières années, on peut estimer qu'un peu moins de la moitié de l'excédent commercial chinois avec les Etats Unis a été converti en bon du trésors (http://www.census.gov/foreign-trade/balance/c5700.html).
Maintenant, un gouvernement comme la France refuse de communiquer sur la répartition par pays de ses créanciers étrangers. Pourtant, en France, la part de la dette publique détenue par des étrangers est bien supérieure à 60% et n'en finit pas de croitre. Quand on sait que le deficit commercial français avec la chine représente la moité de notre déficit commercial global alors que les produits chinois ne représentent que 7.5% de nos importations, on est en droit de se demander quel est le poids de la chine parmi les détenteurs de notre dette publique.
Rédigé par : ST | lundi 13 septembre 2010 à 09h36